2012/12/29

Out the tragedy... fun

It is interesting how a tragedy impresses itself upon the human collective conscience, how it is transformed, in rather unexpected ways. From the holocaust we have books, films, plays. From the financial crisis and its various extensions of financial meltdown we have gotten a Margin Call, a movie with a rather loose grip on reality  (as is the case with most movies) and, I now find, a game called Market Meltdown.

What is it?

The game appears to be based on the antics of a number of rogue traders. In Market Meltdown the players are traders who must make ever bigger bets (as the money they owe increases) in order to stay afloat. The losers are those who go bust first.

Just some fun

It is likely the board game is just good fun, amoral. That is what it is intended to be. It is hard to tell if the game will succeed, whether perhaps people will find it distasteful. But if kids can play computer games pretending to be evil overlords, why not have families play games pretending to be reckless traders. It could be used as an exercise in moral instruction – don’t do this in real life.

But in our hearts

The fact is that there is something about these rogue traders that captures our hearts. Sure, we’re angry with them for being heartless human beings, extensions of a merciless financial sector. But it’s not our money they lost. What a thrill it must be to place such huge bets, to waver between being ignominious Kweku Adoboli or glorious George Soros. (Admittedly Soros was no rogue trader, but his bets were massive and if he were wrong his ignominy would have been as great, if not necessarily prosecutable).

Social commentary

In some sense, the game, with its simplified rules, its exaggerated nature, is a kind of mockery. What were they thinking? We give them, those rogue traders, immortality, not by their reputation, but by frequently reliving their defeat, and laughing at it. Perhaps that, too, is a kind of punishment.

Out of sight

Despite the financial crisis’s impact on people, it being discussed everywhere. Despite the fate of Greece and the entire Eurozone hanging in the balance, I do not think that it is a ripe source of creative inspiration. There are a number of other games inspired by the crisis. Still, I would not imagine that many books of fiction will be written about these times once they are past, that many more films will be made (though there will undoubtedly be some). The halls of finance are just too hard for people to imagine, the dealing and wheedling too obscure, the language too foreign, with certain obvious exceptions, it’s just not exciting enough (although I may be wrong).

It is a pity. Perhaps if we could bring the world of finance to the hearts of people, we could place some heart in finance.

Some references

The game:
  • Clarendon Games, 2012a. Market Meltdown. Available at: http://www.clarendongames.com/product.php?xProd=19 [Accessed December 29, 2012]. Clarendon Games, 2012b. 
  • Market Meltdown Intro. Available at: http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=lq_AdyyiQx4 [Accessed December 29, 2012]. 
The Economist's take:
  • The Economist, 2012. Financial board games: Playing the markets. The Economist. Available at: http://www.economist.com/blogs/prospero/2012/12/financial-board-games [Accessed December 29, 2012]. 
George Soros: 
  • Wikipedia, 2012a. George Soros. Wikipedia. Available at: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Soros [Accessed December 29, 2012]. 
Rogue trader Kweku Adoboli (he is just the most recent):
  •  Wikipedia, 2012b. Kweku Adoboli - Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia. Wikipedia. Available at: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Kweku_Adoboli [Accessed December 29, 2012].

2012/11/17

Backtest blindness


Suppose you have to find a “brilliant” strategy for making money in the markets. You come up with a strategy you think will work. How do you “know” that it will work? One way is to perform backtests. This means you take past investment data, notably share prices, and pretend that you could use your strategy in the past and then see how much money you make.

So let’s suppose your strategy makes a lot of money. In fact, it seems to always make money. What could possibly go wrong? In this post, I will look at a few things that common sense dictate one should consider. A more academic investigation of backtesting will need to wait until a later post.

The curse of finite data

One problem is that you have only tested your strategy on a finite amount of past data. You only “know” it makes money if the future is exactly like this past. How likely is that?

A momentum strategy (involving buying companies whose shares have gone up and selling those whose shares have gone down) is one strategy that seems to perform very well over a very long time period. For instance if you were a quant at a trading desk in 2008 and you backtested such a strategy as far back as say 1940, you might have concluded you had a money-printing machine.

If, however, you had gone as far back as 1930 you would have seen this strategy could wipe out nearly all your capital in just a two month period. And had you implemented the strategy you would have experienced just that in 2009.

The lesson of this is not that you should have backtested all the way to 1930 (although you probably should have). You can only conceivably backtest about that far in any case – we simply do not have data going back much further. Of course a longer backtest is good, but you still have only a finite amount of data.

Markets can and do change

Markets do change, and sometimes quite abruptly. The by-now well-documented implied volatility smile observed in prices did not exist before 1987. Backtesting options strategies on pre-1987 data may not be very useful. The big crash in October seems to have permanently changed the way the market views options. But it could change again.

The problem with “successful” strategies

There is a lot of backtesting going on in financial institutions, I am quite certain. Lots of strategies will never see the light of day because they don’t produce high retrospective returns (they fail the backtest). However, the only strategies you are likely to come across as a potential investor are the ones that succeeded. These strategies have, by process of elimination, been optimised to produce excellent results in past conditions. This is collective data-mining.

These are the most misleading strategies. They are the most likely to disappoint because the past will not repeat itself exactly. This is much like trying to fit a curve to a number of data points – you can fit a curve that matches the data perfectly if you want, but it will have absolutely no predictive power.

Calibration

Calibrating a strategy can be a very dangerous thing to do. If your strategy has a few parameters and you try to find the ones that result in the most profit, you run into exactly the data-mining problem described above. The more parameters the more dangerous this becomes. It helps if you calibrate on one part of the data and test on a separate part. But this does not eliminate the problem – try enough strategies and you will find one that works both in and out of sample and completely fails in real life.

The problem with theories

You may think that if you come up with some brilliant idea, some model of market behaviour, that leads to a great strategy, all will be well. Not necessarily. The problem is that your idea is probably based on working with and observing markets and market data over a period. You are probably more likely to come up with a strategy that works well on past data merely because you know the past data better – even if only intuitively. This does not mean you have found a fundamental market law (perhaps the only fundamental market law is that any trading strategy will fail).

Strategies for which backtests do not work

You cannot backtest everything. Backtests assume you can take the past market prices as given and that you can trade at those prices. This only holds if the amounts you wish to trade are small compared to the volumes traded in the market. Thus backtesting will not work very well in illiquid markets and it will not work if you need buy or sell a large amount of stock that could potentially influence the market price. It is probably good practice to compare the volumes you wish to trade against the volumes actually traded in the past (noting that this changes from day to day).

How to keep the windscreen clear

One way to avoid at least some of the nasties of backtest blindness is to just conceive of a scenario in which your strategy would not make money (or better yet, in which it would lose a lot of money). It does not matter if it’s never happened. It doesn’t matter if it seems unlikely – you are bound to underestimate the probability of it occurring. Prepare for it anyway.

It is useful if whatever strategy you want to implement is based on some underlying theory – a theory that is likely to remain valid even if markets change. For instance, human behaviour is unlikely to change. If your strategy exploits fear and greed, it is more likely to succeed. However, this is no panacea. How do you know you’re actually exploiting human behaviour?

It helps if a strategy works in many markets – it is far more likely you are exploiting some fundamental human behaviour. However, more data is problematic if it gives you false confidence. More data is useful, but it does not negate the problems mentioned.

I admit I am not certain how to avoid all the pitfalls I mentioned above, at least not yet. But being aware of them is much better than not and that is a start.

Some references
  • Barroso, P. & Santa-clara, P., 2012. Managing the Risk of Momentum. Business, (April), pp.1–26. Available at: http://ssrn.com/paper=2041429. Investing Answers, 2012. 
  • Backtesting. Investing Answers . Available at: http://www.investinganswers.com/financial-dictionary/stock-market/backtesting-865 [Accessed November 17, 2012]. 
  • Investopedia, 2012. Backtesting Definition. Investopedia. Available at: http://www.investopedia.com/terms/b/backtesting.asp#axzz2CNdPITKg [Accessed November 17, 2012]. 
  • Wikipedia, 2012. Backtesting. Wikipedia. Available at: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Backtesting [Accessed November 16, 2012]. (not a very good Wikipedia article)

2012/08/13

Review: The Big Short


The Big Short by Michael Lewis is a very good book, thoroughly entertaining. The language is simple, but all the concepts are sufficiently explained to make sense to non-financial readers, without leaving out too much. It also cleared up some issues I have been unable to get a grip on despite reading sporadically about the crisis for years. I do recommend that you read this book. But if you do, beware of a couple of things.

It’s a story

The books reads like a story, which is what makes it so entertaining. But it is also exactly there that its danger lies. It is centred on a handful of individuals that made money from the subprime crisis, who, in essence, predicted it and took investment positions to profit from it.  It contains many personal elements of the lives of these people, explaining how they moved through life and how they decided to place their bets against the system.  Their lives are very interesting, at least Lewis manages to make them appear so.

Don’t trust a story

Storytelling, though useful, is dangerous. It makes you forget how messy life really is. Everything is put into plots and subplots, everything heads toward the ending, in this case, a financial collapse. It has the illusion of inevitability. Never believe that.  As smart as these people were, as thorough as their research was, nothing about their success was inevitable. They were lucky. I do not mean to say the odds were not in their favour – they looked at information most others ignored, they saw things others did not see. But they could (or rather, should not) have been certain. A difference in timing, a slight change in the economy, stimulus here or not there, and we could have seen a different set of winners or losers.

There is a survivorship bias in the book. (This is also a problem with stories – usually they focus on the people who succeed, sometimes on the ones who fail horribly, never the ones in-between). We hear only from the people who made it. How they happened to make their fortune. We don’t hear about the people in similar situations with similar intellects who did not. We are to presume they did not exist.

As I read and I felt the suspense of the coming crash (and voyeuristic  exhilaration at the heaps and heaps of money the protagonists would make) I too felt, perhaps I can make money too, perhaps I could also be a great investor. Of course these people were not really investors, they were speculators betting on the crash of a system (albeit, probably with the odds in their favour).  They were right, at least partly because they were lucky enough to stumble on the right information at the right time.

Disclaimers

Perhaps, if there is anything to learn from the crisis and from the book, it is that you are far more likely to be the sucker who misunderstands everything (in this case almost all of Wall Street) than anything else. Humility is your ally.

I do not mean to say there is anything wrong with the book. It has its uses and its limitations. But perhaps it should contain a disclaimer about the danger of stories.

2012/08/07

Knight in soiled armour

Last week the markets experienced another little jolt, similar to the flash crash in 2010. A computer glitch at Knight Capital caused its systems to send out incorrect orders, causing huge price swings in stocks and driving the company nearly to bankruptcy.

Bugs

There is now talk of changing regulations (again) and everyone wonders what Knight Capital did wrong. They had a bug. I cannot be certain, but my guess is that whatever software they were using had been tested. But with sophisticated systems bugs always slip through (it’s inevitable). Unluckily for Knight their particular bug caused a lot of trouble and damaged the company’s reputation, possibly irreparably.

It’s (almost) all in the mind

What is interesting is that the company is set to survive. Knight was bailed out not by government, but by a handful of its competitors – perhaps they know this could just as easily have happened to them. They were not just being helpful, though. They saw an opportunity to buy a large stake of a good business (potentially good, in any case) very cheaply. The major obstacles to Knight’s continued survival were a lack of capital and loss of confidence. Both were addressed by the bailout. The very fact that these companies were willing to fund Knight will give the market assurance that the business was worth saving.

Reputations

This bailout comes at a price to current shareholders (who are the ones who should pay – not taxpayers and not clients) whose holdings are diluted. Perhaps, slowly, clients will return. The key reason to think this may happen is the reputation of Knight’s CEO, Thomas Joyce, which seems to have been both battered and uplifted in the debacle. Unlike Bob Diamond, CEO of Barclays and other banks’ top brass, Joyce’s integrity is not in question. He has been called a hero for managing to get hold of the much needed financing. Knight also, it seems, absorbed most of the losses – shielding their clients.

What is in question is Knight’s risk management and software testing. And after an incident like this, I think this is liable to become too strict rather than too relaxed. They cannot afford another incident – that would almost certainly end them, if not through a direct loss, then due to a loss of confidence.

Operational risk 

Knight’s problems highlight, once again, that the major risk in business, any business, is operational. It is unpredictable, its costs can be little or gigantic. Even with good risk management procedures (which are a must – and there is no reason to believe Knight’s were not adequate) mistakes will be made. The regulatory reactions to this will (probably) be firstly to increase the amount of capital that companies need to hold so they can absorb operational losses, secondly to mandate more stringent risk management, and thirdly to demand more detailed reports to the regulator (in this case the SEC). All of these things have their costs.

People will, of course, be very interested in knowing what exactly caused the software malfunction and how. And what Knight will be doing to prevent it from happening again. But what the error was hardly matters – it was random. Next time it will be something else. Hopefully responses will focus less on the specific nature of the problem that arose and more on the general nature of operational risk, which has a tendency to pop up in unexpected places.

References
  • Kisling, W., & Mehta, N. (2012). Joyce Puts Knight Survival Over Shares in Rescue Deal. Bloomberg. Retrieved August 7, 2012, from http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2012-08-06/joyce-puts-knight-survival-over-shares-forging-400-million-deal.html
  • Pratley, N. (2012). Knight Capital’s computer “glitch” shows dangers of desire for faster trading. The Guardian. Retrieved August 7, 2012, from http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/nils-pratley-on-finance/2012/aug/06/knight-capital-computer-glitch-trading?newsfeed=true
  • Reuters. (2012). Knight Capital handed $400m lifeline after trading debacle. The Guardian. Retrieved August 7, 2012, from http://www.guardian.co.uk/business/2012/aug/06/knight-capital-400m-lifeline
  • Sapa-AP. (2012). Knight Capital’s $440m computer glitch. Times Live. Retrieved August 7, 2012, from http://www.timeslive.co.za/scitech/2012/08/03/knight-capital-s-440m-computer-glitch
  • The Economist. (2012). Desperate times. The Economist. Retrieved August 7, 2012, from http://www.economist.com/blogs/schumpeter/2012/08/knight-capital?fsrc=scn/fb/wl/bl/desperatetimes
  • Touryalai, H. (2012). Knight Capital: The Ideal Way To Screw Up On Wall Street. Forbes. Retrieved August 7, 2012, from http://www.forbes.com/sites/halahtouryalai/2012/08/06/knight-capital-the-ideal-way-to-screw-up-on-wall-street/

2012/08/03

When to give back the Bacon

My last two posts both were both very critical of ethics in the markets. Today I would like to give some praise. Louis Bacon, manager of a very large fund ($8Bn) of assets has decided to give back a quarter to investors. It is, in essence, admitting defeat. And that is something investment professionals seem to be very loathe to do.

Hedge funds do not like to give back money to investors, even when the investors themselves request it. More assets under management (AUM) means reduced management fees and less prestige. Giving back money also immediately says that you are unable to make money, that you are stumped, that the money is better invested elsewhere. Mr Bacon is giving up about $60m a year (but don’t praise him too much; he is worth over a billion. He is not giving up anything he cannot do without).

Mr Bacon, after recent poor returns, does admit that he just can’t make money in the current environment, not with such a large pool of assets. His fund seems to focus on macro-economic strategies, meaning it makes bets on macro-economic factors affecting countries as whole. Most notably, in this environment, that includes everything affecting the sovereign debt crisis. With all the government intervention and decisions by Ms Merkel (prime minister of Germany) and Mr Draghi (head of the European Central Bank) sending markets up and down, but with no decisive actions being taken, Mr Bacon feels he cannot make a bet on the market movements. He needs to bet something big will happen. And it just won’t happen. Probably Mr Bacon feels he cannot figure out what’s going to happen next, but he hasn’t gone quite as far as admitting that.

A large fund is not as agile as a smaller fund. With a smaller fund Mr Bacon will be able to take smaller positions that have a larger impact on the overall performance of the fund and be able to move in and out of positions more quickly. Hedge funds normally charge a performance fee – if the increase in performance is high enough it may offset the loss of the management fee mentioned earlier.

 Mr Bacon cares for his image. That is why he’d rather try to make a decent return on a smaller fund than poor returns on a larger fund. However, admitting his inability to profit from current market conditions is quite laudable for a man who made his fortune placing bets on other international events equally as murky. He also seems to take his responsibility as a custodian of other people’s money seriously. He cannot give the performance expected and so he has his investors put their money elsewhere. Unfortunately, for many, admitting the limits of their abilities does not seem to come as easily.

References 

  • Chung, J. (2012). Louis Bacon to Return $2 Billion to Investors. Wall Street Journal. Retrieved August 3, 2012, from http://blogs.wsj.com/deals/2012/08/01/louis-bacon-to-return-2-billion-to-investors/ Herbst-Bayliss, S. (2012).
  • Big hedge funds seen unlikely to diet after Bacon slims down. Reuters. Retrieved August 3, 2012, from http://www.reuters.com/article/2012/08/02/us-hedgefunds-idUSBRE8711VN20120802 Thomas Jr., L. (2012).
  • Too Big to Profit, a Hedge Fund Plans to Get Smaller. Dealbook. Retrieved August 3, 2012, from http://dealbook.nytimes.com/2012/08/01/hedge-fund-titan-plans-to-return-2-billion-to-investors/

2012/07/19

Li(e)bor

In my last post I lamented the apparently non-existent moral foundations of banks. I hardly thought the next scandal would be so soon after. Last month it transpired that Barclays had been manipulating the Libor rate. However, everybody else was doing it too, it seems. This is a betrayal of public trust egregious enough, in my opinion (and many others’), to warrant some jail sentences.

But everybody’s doing it

Bankers never seem to do anything alone. Everybody has to have their piece of the pie. No one is willing to stand out, even for the sake of such things as moral principles, ethics, right and wrong. After Barclays was fined a paltry amount it became clear that they were not the only ones involved. A large list of banks is now under investigation. Were they colluding? Probably, but not necessarily. I will discuss this further below. First, let us get a grip on what this mysterious Libor is.

What is the Libor?

Libor, actually LIBOR , is an acronym for London Interbank Offered Rate. It seems to be an interest rate. Actually, it is not, which is part of the problem. It should, however, in principle at least, be related to actual interest rates. The interest rates referred to are the rates banks charge each other when they lend money to each other. It is a common occurrence for a bank to lend money to another bank, for instance if the latter bank needs liquidity in the short term. The Libor is calculated more or less as follows. A number of banks (16, it seems) are asked to give an estimate of the rate at which they could borrow money from the inter-bank market. The top and bottom quarter of these estimates are thrown out and an average taken of the ones that remain. This is the Libor. The problem with the above process is that it is open to manipulation. It is subjective, which makes it easier (and more tempting) to lie. This, then is what Barclays did. What many banks did.

Why does it matter if Libor is wrong?

Libor might not be an actual interest rate, but many (very many) actual interest rates are based directly on Libor, from mortgage rates to rates on derivatives known as swaps. If Libor is low it means those with mortgages related to Libor pay lower amounts. They win. However, people invested in instruments that pay rates related to Libor lose out as they get less. These may not even out. The impact of a single basis point difference in Libor is a huge redistribution of wealth. Libor matters not only because of instruments it affects directly. It has become a global benchmark interest rate. It is taken into account in many decisions. It could affect many other rates charged, advice given, corporate actions taken. The Libor is also an indicator of the health of the banking system. When it is high, it indicates banks have little faith in the ability of their peers to repay their money. An artificially low Libor rate is, in effect, a collective denial of the fragility of the banking system. It is serious if such a globally significant figure is a lie.

Why try to manipulate Libor?

  1. In order to look better. For a time Barclays’ submitted Libor figures were higher than the rest of the market. This, seemingly, indicated that Barclays was in relatively poor health. Lowering its Libor estimates alleviated these fears.
  2. Because everybody else is doing it. Why were the other banks’ Libor estimates so low? Possibly because they were underreporting them. Barclays may not have been the first to do so. The more banks that underreport their Libor the more pressure there is on other banks to do the same in order not to seem weak. In addition, if everybody else is doing it, it is far easier to delude yourself into thinking it is acceptable. You can defend yourself by pointing fingers. 
  3. Profit. Profit. Profit. Emails between those responsible for the submission of Libor and traders show agreements to attempt to manipulate Libor in order to favour the traders’ positions. For instance, suppose Barclays held a swap contract in which they agreed to pay a the Libor rate to another party and, in return, received a fixed rate1. If the Libor rate falls, the bank’s position becomes more valuable as it is now paying out a smaller amount, but still receiving the same fixed amount.


What does it matter if Barclay’s Libor is wrong?

Barclays is only one bank. Does it really matter if its Libor submission is wrong? Well, yes and no. If Barclays submission is too high or too low it does not influence the calculated result at all. However, every bank’s submission influences every other banks’ submission. None of the banks would want to seem too weak compared to the others. This can lead to seemingly co-ordinated underreporting of Libor even if the banks are not colluding explicitly. This, however, is really only relevant for reasons 1 and 2 above. To profit from Libor rigging, Barclays would need to be able to move the rate on its own, unless it colluded with other banks which had similar positions.

Let us suppose Barclays’ estimate is not thrown out, so it is one of the eight estimates that do get averaged. What is the effect of Barclays’ estimate? Suppose the average of the other 7 banks is x and the Barclays estimate b (in per cent), then the average of all 8 is 7/8x + b/8. How much lower than the average of the other banks would Barclay’s estimate need to be in order to lower the Libor by 1 basis point, that is by 0.01? Solving a simple linear equation gives that Barclays’ estimate should be 8 basis points lower. Conversely, to push up Libor by one basis point, Barclays’ estimate needed to be 8 basis points higher. To give a little more perspective: In 2005/6 Libor was around 5% at times. If Barclays’ wanted to lower the Libor to 4.99, it needed to submit an estimate of 4.92. It might not have needed to manipulate it any more than that to profit. Now, I am no expert on Libor rates or their spreads. It may be that the spread in Libor estimates was high enough to allow Barclays’ estimate to be included in the average. In any case, presumably those submitting the rates would know more or less, from experience, what kind of range of values are usually submitted and adjust the submission accordingly. So, it seems that it was possible for Barclays’ to manipulate Libor, albeit in a somewhat limited fashion. It also appears that traders did in fact collude so that several banks altered their submissions simultaneously. This would have a far greater influence on the Libor estimate.

Should bankers go to jail?

Yes. This is an example of fraud (albeit committed by almost an entire industry). I hope to see several people behind bars for this. However, whether that will happen, given the widespread nature of the fraud and the possible difficulty in assigning culpability, I do not know. What is clear is that the fines imposed for this kind of behaviour are ineffective. They do not even make a dent in the Banks’ balance sheets. Lawsuits against Barclays may do more damage, though.

Are regulators also to blame?

It seems that regulators knew Libor was incorrect for quite some time. And did nothing. In the midst of the financial crisis they probably thought there were more pressing concerns. Perhaps they just did not want to believe that what they were told was true, and so they didn’t. Bernanke apparently knew of the troubles with Libor and told the British regulators, who did not take it seriously. So the British regulators are clearly at fault. However, morally, Bernanke is too. Here is one of the greatest financial scams in history, affecting millions of people, and you keep silent, you don’t make a public statement, you don’t force a resolution. You say in the gentlemen’s club. Something similar can be said of Tim Geithner, president of the New York Fed at the time the rigging occurred.

What to do?

Of course, Libor is now useless. I think the best thing to do would be to replace it with a similar rate, but based on actual transactions. This has been suggested by others. Of course, everyone is calling for tougher regulation. Probably, the entire structure of regulating bodies will need to be changed. It’s no use for there to be good regulation if it is not enforced. The relationship between regulators and the industry is clearly not working. Perhaps we should all start putting our money in Triodos. At least these bankers seem to have a conscience. Or perhaps we should just mutualise all the banks. No more shareholders and banks owned by depositors. Less profit motive. Perhaps the incentives would be less perverse, but honestly, I am not sure. Ideally, people would grow spines, come to believe in a higher power, or just start caring about other people, but that won’t happen.

Post-apocalypse

We have not, it seems, heard the last of this particular scandal. The investigation of other banks is going to take a while and will, hopefully, unearth some corpses. A good article says the following:

The unpalatable message of the crisis and Diamond's actions – or inaction – is that financial institutions can't be trusted to not act foolishly in pursuit of their own self interest, and that the only question is how frequently they do so and how grave the consequences prove to be either for their shareholders or for the financial system as a whole.

Banks have demonstrated time and again that they are devoid of moral rectitude, that they act selfishly and (economists would rejoice) rationally in the face of temptation. And why should they not? We always let them off the hook. As one article puts it “there’s something rotten in banking.”

References

News 
  • Barr, R. (2012). Former Barclays exec admits false LIBOR submission. Newsday. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://newyork.newsday.com/news/region-state/former-barclays-exec-admits-false-libor-submission-1.3840836 
  • Barrow, B., & Davies, R. (2012). Bob Diamond DID give orders to cut Libor, claims Barclays executive . Mail Online. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://www.dailymail.co.uk/news/article-2174614/Bob-Diamond-DID-orders-cut-Libor-claims-Barclays-executive.html 
  • Bloomberg. (2012). There’s Something Rotten in Banking . Bloomberg View. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2012-07-02/barclays-case-shows-something-s-rotten-in-banking-culture.html 
  • Bloomberg News. (2012). NY among states probing interest-rate fixing. Newsday. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://newyork.newsday.com/news/region-state/ny-among-states-probing-interest-rate-fixing-1.3843206 
  • Crutsinger, M. (2012). Bernanke: Fed had no power to change LIBOR. Newsday. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://newyork.newsday.com/news/region-state/bernanke-fed-had-no-power-to-change-libor-1.3843208 
  • DuBois, S. (2012). The Barclays school of crisis management. CNN Money. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://management.fortune.cnn.com/2012/07/03/the-barclays-school-of-crisis-management/?iid=SF_F_River 
  • Farrell, M. (2012). Barclays: Don’t just blame us! CNN Money. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://buzz.money.cnn.com/2012/07/03/barclays-libor-investigation/?iid=EL 
  • McGee, S. (2012). The Big Questions Raised by the Barclays Scandal. The Fiscal Times. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://www.thefiscaltimes.com/Columns/2012/07/05/The-Big-Questions-Raised-by-the-Barclays-Scandal.aspx#page1 
  • Morris, N. (2012). Other banks face bigger fines on rate fixing, warn Barclays directors. The Independent. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://www.independent.co.uk/news/business/news/other-banks-face-bigger-fines-on-rate-fixing-warn-barclays-directors-7945444.html 
  • O’Toole, J. (2012). Explaining the Libor interest rate mess. CNN Money. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://money.cnn.com/2012/07/03/investing/libor-interest-rate-faq/index.htm 
  • Reuters. (2012). RBS set for fine as Barclays boss remains defiant. The Fiscal Times. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://latestnews.thefiscaltimes.com/2012/06/28/uk-banks-face-new-scandal-barclays-boss-in-peril/ 
  • Reuters. (2012). Barclays takes rate fixing scandal hit. Business Report. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://www.iol.co.za/business/international/barclays-takes-rate-fixing-scandal-hit-1.1341163 
  • Rosenberg, Y. (2012). Libor-gate Explained: Why Barclays’ Scandal Matters. The Fiscal Times. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://www.thefiscaltimes.com/Articles/2012/07/06/Libor-gate-Explained-Why-Barclays-Scandal-Matters.aspx#page1 
  • Sky News. (2012). Barclays Was “In Denial” Over Rate-Fixing. Sky News HD. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://news.sky.com/story/961370/barclays-was-in-denial-over-rate-fixing

An interesting blogger
  • Doyle, L. (2012). Barclays Libor Scandal: Reports Regulators Knew; Time for Independent Investigation and Eliot Spitzer. Sense on Cents. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://www.senseoncents.com/2012/07/barclays-libor-scandal-reports-regulators-knew-time-for-independent-investigation-and-eliot-spitzer/ 
  • Doyle, L. (2012). Barclays Libor Scandal: When Did Manipulation Start? Sense on Cents. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://www.senseoncents.com/2012/07/barclays-libor-scandal-when-did-manipulation-start/
  • Doyle, L. (2012). Barclays Libor Scandal: Who’s Really to Blame? Sense on Cents. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://www.senseoncents.com/2012/07/barclays-libor-scandal-whos-really-to-blame/ Doyle, L. (2012). Barclays Libor Scandal: “Diamond Lied.” Sense on Cents. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://www.senseoncents.com/2012/07/barclays-libor-scandal-diamond-lied-to-the-committee/ 
  • Doyle, L. (2012). Barclays Libor Scandal: Holding Regulators to Account. Sense on Cents. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://www.senseoncents.com/2012/07/barclays-libor-scandal-holding-regulators-to-account/ 
  • Doyle, L. (2012). Barclays Libor Scandal: The Precedent. Sense on Cents. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://www.senseoncents.com/2012/07/barclays-libor-scandal-the-precedent/#more-30091
  • Doyle, L. (2012). Barclays scandal: How big will this get? CNN Money. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://finance.fortune.cnn.com/2012/07/03/barclays-libor-scandal/?iid=EL 
Some graphs 
  • FedPrimeRate.com. (2012). LIBOR rates: Historical Charts. FedPrimeRate.com. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://www.fedprimerate.com/libor/libor_rates_history-chart-graph.htm 
Wikipedia
  • Wikipedia. (2012). Libor scandal. Wikipedia. Retrieved July 18, 2012, from http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Libor_scandal

1 This is a common arrangement. An organization may for instance have a variable rate loan which it needs to repay with a floating interest rate. In order to make its costs more certain, it can enter a swap contract with a bank, pay a fixed amount every month and in return the bank will pay the interest on the loan.

2012/06/12

Another day, another embarrassment

It seems that Wall Street never misses an opportunity to embarrass itself. The most recent scandal is a multi-billion (read milliard in strictly correct British English) dollar trading loss at JP Morgan. The exact value of this trade (or rather collection of trades) will only become known when it is finally unwound. Details of what happened are sketchy and likely to remain so.


Why don't we know what happened?

At least partially we don't know because JP Morgan won't tell us. In fact the market probably already knows far more than JP Morgan would like. As long as the trade is not completely wound down, it is bad for the bank if others know exactly what it has been up to, because then they can more easily trade against it. In fact the market has already done so, magnifying the loss. More fundamentally, however, we don't know because nobody knows, perhaps not even the trader, known as the “London Whale” who initiated the trades. It is somewhat frightening to think that such things can happen without the CEO knowing, but one man can only know so much and there is just too much too know in an organisation so large. Ironically, JP Morgan ended up betting against itself – one unit of the company took the opposite position to the loss-making trade, offsetting part of the losses.


The department of mysteries

The unit of JP Morgan where this loss took place, the Chief Investment Office, appears to be a bit of a mystery. It has been described as being "charged with managing the bank’s idle cash to earn a profit while minimizing risk". Well, if it really were doing that, it should not have taken such huge bets, not under any circumstances. Other reports say it was meant to hedge risk. This means it was supposed to enter into trades that would minimize possible losses on other positions. From what little is known of the trades involved, though, they seemed more like pure speculation (although some of the losses were offset by other positions in the company). I can imagine that the trades were in a kind of gray area – hedge-like enough to put through as legitimate and too profitable (at least momentarily) to really question. What is clear, though is that the operations in the CIO and its links with other departments failed and they failed horribly. This was not really a trading loss. It was an operational loss, caused by the failure of proper risk management, proper oversight and proper communication.


Whose fault is it?

A lot of blame has been dished out. The trader involved has taken a lot of blame. It does not, however, appear that he was a rogue trader. He was making ill-advised bets, yes, but his trades were signed off, it seems. He may even have thought he really was hedging risk (rather than creating it). The person at the head of the CIO, of course should (and has) taken much blame. And so has Jamie Dimon, JP Morgan's CEO. He deserves blame, not for not being aware of these trades (he cannot know what every individual trader is doing), but for ignoring reports about these trades when they surfaced before the loss became evident.


The problem with complexity

A part of the problem, perhaps, lies in complexity. The trades that caused this huge loss were, it seems, very complex and interconnected. Built up over a number of years, they could have grown in complexity to the point where even their progenitor did not fully understand them. JP Morgan itself is a frighteningly complex institution (I admit I looked at its wiki page and did not even try to unravel its intricacies). Human minds cannot handle such complexity. We need to cordon off specific elements, simple enough to comprehend, to specific people and groups. The people at the top must handle the big picture, which can be made simple enough, but they cannot know all the details. In such an environment things get lost, things are forgotten, and errors are made. Ultimately accountability is hard to assign because no one (or two, or even three people) knew enough to have done something. This, of course, plays right into the "too big to fail" debate because bigger institutions are more complex. However, it is not clear to me that forcing these institutions to split into smaller ones would help (they became this big for a reason, so being big does have advantages).

Is it really a problem?

On the one hand this loss represents an egregious failure within JP Morgan. On the other hand, we should expect such losses (operational and otherwise) to occur from time to time. If you invest in stocks you don't always expect them to go up. If you have a large institution you don't expect everything to always go like clockwork. What regulators have attempted to do is to ensure that banks have enough capital to absorb these losses. At least, in this case, the loss was easily covered and only made a little dent in the bank's balance sheet. The instinctive response of more and stricter regulation may not be the right one, not if it increases complexity even further.


The final curtain

The details of the trade and the loss, perhaps, are not all that important. The point is that yet another financial institution has (for not the first time in its history) proven that it cannot be trusted. JP Morgan was in the thick of the speculation in 1930s and now we have this loss. I imagine it was not blameless in the raging financial crisis either. I plan to work in the financial sector. I hope I do not one day have to say "We know we were sloppy. We know we were stupid."

Some references

  • Campbell, D., 2012. JPMorgan Faces $4.2 Billion Trading Loss. Huff Post Business. Available at: http://www.huffingtonpost.com/2012/06/05/jpmorgan-chases-trading-l_n_1570578.html [Accessed June 11, 2012]. 
  • Campbell, D., 2012. JPMorgan Faces $4.2 Billion Trading Loss, ISI Forecasts - Bloomberg. Bloomberg. Available at: http://www.bloomberg.com/news/2012-06-04/jpmorgan-faces-4-2-billion-trading-loss-isi-forecasts.html [Accessed June 11, 2012]. 
  • LaCapra, L.T., 2012. JPMorgan trading loss shows danger in bank size -Volcker. Reuters. Available at: http://uk.reuters.com/article/2012/06/07/uk-jpmorgan-volcker-idUKBRE85615720120607 [Accessed June 11, 2012]. 
  • Macke, J., 2012. JP Morgan Trading Loss: Still More Questions Than Answers. Yahoo! Finance. Available at: http://finance.yahoo.com/blogs/breakout/jp-morgan-trading-loss-still-more-questions-answers-154010320.html [Accessed June 11, 2012]. 
  • Schwartz, N.D. & Silver-Greenberg, J., 2012. JPMorgan’s Trading Loss Is Said to Rise at Least 50%. New York Times. Available at: http://dealbook.nytimes.com/2012/05/16/jpmorgans-trading-loss-is-said-to-rise-at-least-50/ [Accessed June 11, 2012]. 
  • Smith, A. & Thomasch, P., 2012. JPMorgan $2 billion loss hits shares, dents image. Reuters. Available at: http://www.reuters.com/article/2012/05/11/us-jpmorgan-trading-idUSBRE8491H020120511 [Accessed June 11, 2012]. 
  • Wikipedia, 2012. 2012 JPMorgan Chase trading loss. Wikipedia. Available at: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/2012_JPMorgan_Chase_trading_loss. 
  • Zuckerman, G. & Burne, K., 2012. “London Whale” Rattles Debt Market. Wall Street Journal. Available at: http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052702303299604577326031119412436.html [Accessed June 11, 2012].

2012/02/04

Break out the bubbly

Bubbles are fascinating market phenomena. They often end with a devastating crash – these occasions etch themselves into collective human memory because of the psychological devastation they cause. In retrospect it is almost always obvious that values were inflated, that the market was exceedingly fragile and that the good times would not last. But in the midst of the bubble all except a wise (and ignored) few are blind. It seems a fundamental flaw of human nature dooms us to repeating the same mistake time and again.

Famous bubbles

In order to entrench that what we call bubbles are real events, rather than just an academic construct, I think it is useful to list some of the more famous bubbles in world history.

Tulip mania (1585 - 1650): People invested heavily in tulips, a Dutch export. The price of tulip bulbs shot up as people mortgaged their houses and businesses to trade in tulips. In 1637, bulbs which people used to pay for dearly become nearly worthless when the bubble burst.

South Sea Bubble(1720): It is actually after this episode that the term “bubble” was coined. Here speculation was based on expectations of profitable trade with Spanish colonies in South America. This is a good example financial manipulation. The directors of the South Sea Company deliberately sought to drive up its stock price - this was done by creating an artificial hype around trading possibilities. A number of bogus companies (and some bona fide ones) also tried to cash in and swindled many investors. A famous example was a bogus company “for carrying on an undertaking of great advantage, but nobody to know what it is”. The bubble burst slowly but definitively, bankrupting many.

Roaring twenties (1922 – 1929): The stock market was the place to be. The man-on-the-street started investing in stocks – everyone thought they could make a fortune, and quickly. Many invested in the market with borrowed money. This time it was new industries that were thought be able to bring permanent prosperity. Bankers came under fire after 1929 for manipulating the market and bolstering the speculation. The crash of 1929 and the resulting depression are well known.

Dot com bubble (1995- 2000): With the advent of the internet, speculation in internet and technology companies took place. It was thought the old rules did not apply to this new industry.

These are just the more famous bubbles. There are many more examples of varying devastation. The financial crisis was partly caused by the bursting of a housing bubble in America. The unsavoury lending practices associated with this bubble are by now well known. Not all bubbles end in crashes. In the 1960s there was a bubble associated with electronic manufacturing, which ended less spectacularly than the examples described and as a result it has not earned a prominent place in history.

Bubbles are characterised by some defining features:

  1. There is a belief that prices will continue to rise indefinitely
  2. There is an overwhelming belief that (1) can be justified as circumstances are somehow different from previous bubbles. In the 1920’s it was “The New Era” of industry, in the 1990’s it was the “New Economy” caused by the internet.
  3. People exhibit a willingness to believe bordering on stupidity. People may be fooled by swindlers, by bankers, and, often, themselves. All that’s needed is an excuse to believe. No more.
  4. People purchase stocks (or other assets) purely for their resale value – the dividends or income from the asset become secondary and, in fact, may be traded away. For instance in the 1920’s people were willing to pay interest rates on loans far higher than the earnings on stocks hoping to sell the stock later at a higher price.
  5. There tend to be high levels of speculation, which can be taken to mean making risky investments with the possibility of a complete loss of capital, usually with borrowed money.
  6. The dismissal of “prophets of doom” who forecast the end of the bubble
  7. Right up until the end, everything seems good. There seems only to be cause for optimism. The cracks only seem to appear later.
  8. People focus on the fact that prices go up, rather than why they go up. Inevitably the why is that people expect prices to go up. So they go up.
  9. When the end comes people are reluctant to believe it. But efforts to revive the bubble inevitably fail.
  10. There is a “failure to know what isn’t known” as Galbraith puts it. People act is if they are knowledgeable – of course this stock will go up – but they do not know that they do not actually know.

How do bubbles form?

The origins of bubbles are not clear. We can identify some conditions which seem to be necessary and a number of others that help bubbles along.

Looking for a definite cause may be misleading – the structure of the market itself may be the cause. This is, essentially, what the dynamical systems models, as in my earlier post, posit. Here it is a process of contagion of opinion between investors that causes the bubble. People are optimistic because others are optimistic, which causes more people to become optimistic. All that’s needed is an initial spark and enough optimism to be generated from it. This is not deterministic – it’s an inherently random process.

It is clear that optimism is essential. People have to believe the story of the era to be tempted to invest. They need to blind to the risks they are taking. People need to have faith in others – mistrust results in caution, which does not favour speculation.

It helps if there is a large supply of savings. If this is the case people will be more willing to risk a part of their savings in the market (Economists would say that the marginal value of savings diminishes with increasing savings). In addition the availability of credit would make speculation easier. It allows people to buy far more stocks, driving prices higher. These are contributing factors, not a causes.

This suggests, then, that speculation-fuelled bubbles are more likely after a period of prosperity, which builds up confidence and savings, and may also result in fewer credit restrictions. The memory of previous bubbles and hardships needs to dull. As such it may be some time before the next bubble after the latest financial crisis appears. But it will come.

Why do bubbles burst?

It is tempting to think that bubbles burst because something happens. In the efficient markets view a huge crash must be caused by some dramatic and unexpected news. This does not seem to be the case. In hindsight, it is always possible to say this event or that caused the selling. But more often than not, there is no good reason why that event should have had such a catastrophic effect.

Dynamical systems theory, as mentioned in my earlier post, gives an alternative explanation. The truth is that after a period of speculation, the market is in an unstable state. A large number of market participants are acting in unison. All that is needed for a crash is for them all to decide to sell at once. The truth is that just about anything can cause this to happen, say slightly worse than expected economic figures. The true underlying cause of the crash is the bubble that caused the market to be in such an unstable state, not the event that bursts the bubble.

Bubbles seem to rely on a supply of new buyers, to whom those who want to cash in can sell. We may call these buyers fools, as they are purchasing an overvalued asset. However, they expect to sell to a “greater fool” who will purchase the asset at an even higher price. When this supply of greater fools dries up (as it inevitably does), prices decelerate.

When confidence diminishes, even just a little, it can cause the bubble to burst. The first wave of speculators sell, causing others to sell as well. Pessimism rapidly infects the market and sellers swamp buyers. If there were sales on margin, this can exacerbate the matter as these generally come with margin requirements. Speculators need to put up money as collateral for the stocks they bought on credit. The lower the price of the stock, the more of this money called margin is needed. Falling prices will cause some margin buyers to be forced to sell when they can no longer put up more margin, which drives prices down further.

Bubbles can be burst by regulatory action. The central bank can raise interest rates, for instance. Even just a statement by the bank that assets are overvalued could do it. But this immediately identifies who ended the bubble and opens up the authorities up for criticism. As such, this is not generally how bubbles burst.

A litany against arrogance

Having now examined history, I may be tempted to think I am immune to the kind of mass deception that characterises bubbles. This would be a mistake. If I have learnt anything, it is that bubbles are complex and subtle, and that human nature being what it is, cannot easily digest subtlety. I am human and have the same flaws. It is, perhaps, even more tempting to think that great minds (through introspection or rational deliberation) may be immune. Few would challenge the greatness of Irving Fisher, whose work pervades economics and statistics even today. In a statement now famous, 14 days before the crash, Fisher said that “In a few months, I expect to see the stock market much higher than today.” Fallibility is pervasive. There is some (cold) comfort if one recognises that markets are random, that some things cannot be explained or predicted, that knowledge is superficial at best.

Some references

An excellent account of the 1929 crash:
  • Galbraith, J. K. (1997). The Great Crash 1929. New York: Houghton Mifflin Company.
From a dynamical systems viewpoint:
  • Sornette, D. (2003). Why stock markets crash. Woodstock: Princeton University Press.
Wikipedia:
  • Wikipedia. (2012). Speculation. Wikipedia. Retrieved February 4, 2012 from http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Speculation
  • Wikipedia. (2012). Dot-com bubble. Wikipedia. Retrieved February 4, 2012 from http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Dotcom_bubble
  • Wikipedia. (2012). Economic bubble. Wikipedia. Retrieved February 2, 2012 from http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Economic_bubble

2012/01/31

Don’t look at my crystal ball: predicting crashes

Stock market crashes seem to hit with a ferocity and suddenness that suggests we cannot possibly predict their occurrence. With previous crashes, including in 1929, there have been those who argued that a crash was coming because speculation could not be sustained. In “Why stock markets crash: critical events in complex financial systems” Didier Sornette argues that he has found a scientific way to predict crashes.

Heisenberg uncertainty for markets

The problem with predicting stock market crashes is that prediction changes the market. If you make your prediction public, either
  1. very few people believe you and the stock market crashes on its own, or it does not crash because your prediction was wrong; or
  2. a large number of people believe you. They get out of the market or worse, go short. The prediction causes the crash; or
  3. a sizeable number of people believe the prediction may be correct. They adjust. Rather than crash, the market merely wanes. The prediction prevents the crash.
Such a prediction has very little hope of being credible. If the market crashes either you caused the crash, or you were probably just lucky. Preventing the crash, a social good, necessarily destroys your credibility. The only way to make a prediction, then, is to do so in secret. Leave the prediction with a notary who will reveal it after the fact. This is what Sornette did.

There seems to me to be another problem with prediction and that is with the methods used. If you choose to publish your method, this is essentially the same as making very many future predictions public, provided of course people actually use the model. In this case, either the model becomes a good approximation of reality or, quite the opposite, it fails to predict crashes because people adjust correctly whenever the model predicts a crash will occur. The former case is likely to be unstable. It will create a pattern from which traders could profit.

In any case, if you want to make money from your model, you should probably keep it secret. And Sornette has done this as well, not publishing his latest models. The ones I relate here were probably published with some delay.

The mathematics

Sornette tries very hard to describe his models without heavy mathematics and to explain things in a way that a lay man would understand. He fails miserably in this task. With the talk of spontaneous symmetry breaking, goldstone modes, and log-periodic behaviour (concepts from physics and dynamical systems), I was entirely lost. I am no physicist, but I consider myself to be a sophisticated reader and I got no more than the gist of things.

Sornette’s method is based on identifying the log-periodic signature associated with a speculative bubble. Such a bubble, characterised by rapidly rising prices, must eventually burst or wind down. Prices cannot continue to rise at a super-exponential rate forever, as then they will reach infinity in a finite amount of time. There is a point in time at which a crash is then most likely to occur and this is what Sornette tries to find.

Inherent in this is the idea that there is something special about a crash, and the events that precede it. Crashes are not just price drops on a larger scale. They have special properties. If this were not the case, prediction would be impossible.

Here is a horribly simplified version of the model (which I will present without a proper justification for why markets should follow such a pattern). We can suppose that during a speculative bubble the logarithm of prices follows, roughly, a power law of the following form

log(P(t)) = A + B(tc – t)D

With 0 < D < 1 we see that the gradient of the function becomes infinite at tc and the log-price reaches a maximum value of A at this point. tc is the most likely point for the bubble to burst and a crash to ensue. However, the crash can occur earlier and it need not occur at all, if prices wind down more gently. The figure plots one example of such a power law for the 1987 crash with tc = 87.65.

The above figure plots the power-law formula as fitted for a period just before the 1987 crash of the Dow Jones index. (Created using Wolfram Alpha)
Ad absurdum

It is one thing to predict stock market crashes. When the economy is in a speculative frenzy, there are always a few sober individuals who realise it cannot last. It is another thing to predict the course of world events. Sornette applies his techniques to population statistics and other figures to conclude that something, the singularity, is going to happen around 2050. What will it be? Who knows? Sornette provides some fluffy speculation. I suspect this last chapter was added merely to increase sales and should not be taken seriously.

Track record

Sornette reports a small number of actual predictions (made before the events took place). Five crash predictions were made. Two were false alarms, and two (or three, depending on how loosely you define ‘crash’) were successes. This is, of course, a terribly small sample. But even predicting two crashes correctly is something. One can do some math to say whether it is really significant (and Sornette does), but I mistrust such endeavours. Needless to say, I need more convincing.

What is the use?

You can do two things with your ability to predict crashes. You can make money, or at least avoid losses, and you can help prevent future crashes. If people believe the model works, when a crash seems likely to be coming, speculation should slow. The market could become more stable (in fact, it is not clear that it might not rather cause the opposite). Authorities could use the model to decide when to step in. The problem is, if this works, the model will now be a bad predictor of crashes.

It is also precisely when action is needed the most when the model is least likely to be trusted. In a speculative orgy, people want to believe the good times will continue. The model would have failed before. Perhaps it is wrong this time too. I do not believe the Sornette model is likely to have this effect, merely because it does not appear to have been widely adopted. Even if crashes do not occur as predicted by the model, this does not mean they will not occur. They may develop a new pattern, one the model cannot account for.

Final word

Stock market prediction is a perilous business. At best it is imprecise, unreliable. At worst it attracts charlatans and those who would manipulate markets for their own ends. In the midst of a speculative frenzy it seems that we should know better; we should know things cannot last. We seem to be unwilling to predict the end. We can neither trust our models nor our instincts. The former are too simple, the latter too susceptible to fallibility.

References

Sornette, D. (2003). Why stock markets crash. Woodstock: Princeton University Press.

2012/01/26

Blink and trade

I just finished reading the (highly recommended) book Blink by Malcolm Gladwell. It is about those decisions humans can make instantaneously, without conscious thought. It’s about when this works extremely well, and when it fails, sometimes with horrible consequences. My own decisions are the opposite of snap judgements. I consider everything with extreme care, perhaps too much care. Traders often do not have that luxury, especially not, I think, pit traders. What interests me then, is to what extent traders rely on snap judgements and is this a good thing?

Traders, war games and money

Gladwell relates a tale about General Van Riper, at a time when the US government was conducting very expensive war games. Van Riper thought there was something to be learnt from trading, and so the army played some trading games. What is more, he took some traders to play war games and found that they were very good. They were able to make the rapid assessments under high pressure that were needed. It was clear that the army and traders were “fundamentally engaged in the same business – the only difference being that one group bet on money and the other bet on lives.” George Soros, reportedly, owes much of his success to this kind of instinctive decision-making. His back starts to hurt and he changes his market position.

The good, the bad, the ugly

Blink decisions can be very good. They avoid over-analysis. They allow people to react within the necessary amount of time. And they can, under the right circumstances, be as good or better than decisions made with careful and tiresome deliberation.

The problem, of course, is getting those right circumstances. Snap judgements can fail horribly, such as when a policy officer shoots an unarmed suspect, seeing a gun that was never there. But such snap judgements can also allow you to avoid getting killed. In general, experience and practice, allow for better snap judgements. Is it thus possible for traders to get a feel for the markets based on their experience, a sense, a tingling, that they cannot perhaps explain, that allows them to avoid losses or make profits?

The problem is that markets are so very random. The information a trader sees is peppered with irrelevancies. There is, perhaps, no pattern. Our brains are very good at sifting through information and focussing on what’s really important. But it can also get fooled. I am not sure whether the markets are more likely to fool the brain or not. All the evidence for biases in human decision-making would suggest caution is warranted.

It is usually thought that deliberated decisions should be at least as good as snap judgements. This is often not the case. We can get swamped by information. We make errors because we cannot identify what is truly relevant. We get distracted by things we might be better off not considering. In the markets, more information is not necessarily better. Much of it is irrelevant, meaningless, in any case.

Snap judgements, of course, cannot be scrutinised. The mechanisms behind them are hidden from our conscious minds. We cannot, rationally, justify them. “I had a feeling,” is not a good enough explanation for entering a trade that lost a lot of money. And, even if some traders were good at making such snap decisions, not all of them would be. It might be hard to distinguish them.

Final word

I do not think this is a topic which has been much studied. I can, therefore do little but pose some interesting questions. Are trader snap judgements good? Can they be improved with training or by changing the environment in which those decisions are made (such as limiting the information a trader sees)? Should traders rely more or less on snap judgements?

Reference

Gladwell, M. (2005). Blink. New York: Little, Brown and Company.

2012/01/24

Markets as complex systems

Markets are driven by people (and, lately, algorithms). Their decisions (driven by their motives) drive prices. However, economic theory has had little to say about how these interactions ‘add up’ to give the aggregate market dynamics we observe. It is a convenient excuse to say that markets are efficient, and so what we observe must be because of news events, which people immediately react on and incorporate in prices. This seems a little fanciful. We may consider instead what some have called the interacting agents hypothesis, which says that we can explain (inefficient) market behaviour by looking at the aggregation of individual interactions. I recently examined a class of models based on dynamical systems theory that does just this.

What we are trying to explain

In virtually all markets a number of stylised facts have been found. The ones that contradict the standard model of financial markets (the random walk model) have often been called anomalies, as if they are aberrant and infrequent. They are not. It is the standard model that is aberrant. Here are the things I mean

Unit roots

Standard tests of whether markets follow a random walk (whether they have a unit root) are unable to reject it. This would, on its own, seem to confirm the standard model. However, there is ample other evidence of market behaviour to reject it. That these standard tests thus still give this result is very interesting.

Fat tails

Market returns exhibit fat tails. Technically, it means that they have a distribution with a high kurtosis. This means that very large price movements as well as negligible price movements occur more frequently than the standard model would predict. A very interesting feature of the returns distribution is that the fat tails are observed for daily returns, but monthly and yearly returns appear to be approximately normal. One could argue that even daily returns are made of thousands of intra-daily returns – if these followed the standard model, the daily returns would have a normal distribution by the central limit theorem. Why is it not applying, or why is it acting so slowly? The interacting agents models attempt to explain it by including dependencies between agents (remember that the central limit theorem needs independent observations).

Volatility clustering

The market has periods of relative calm interspersed with periods of highly volatile prices. The autocorrelations absolute returns (and to lesser extent squared returns) is high. Markets are well-behaved most of the time, but sometimes something happens....

Dynamical systems

Dynamical systems theory, also known as chaos theory is a branch of mathematics that looks at the interactions of many particles. Non-linear interactions (even if each particle behaves according to a relatively simple set of rules) can result in surprisingly rich behaviour of the system as a whole, know as emergent properties. I have mentioned chaos theory before because it naturally leads to power law behaviour. These systems may have infrequent but sudden transitions, corresponding to critical points (or singularities) where the system makes a transition from disorder to order. Such properties may explain the relative calmness of markets most of the time, interspersed with periods of volatility.

The models

The models I have looked at use two kinds of agents, chartists and fundamentalists. The former are technical analysts, trend followers. They are supposed to exaggerate market movements. The latter believe the market will return to its fundamental price. They are supposed to have a stabilising effect on prices as they buy when prices are below fundamental value and sell when they are above. I have written about these investment philosophies before.

The basic mechanism of these models is imitation. Chartists may be optimistic (buyers) or pessimistic (sellers). This mood (of optimism or pessimism) can spread from trader to trader like a virus. As such it can be called contagion, infection, or herding. This is a simple way of modelling trader psychology. There is a force that results in people getting on the bandwagon. And the more people there are on already, the stronger the force. This is not necessarily irrational. It makes sense to look at the opinions of your peers as this provides information (especially if you do not have other information). For traders it may be very important not to underperform the rest of the market (as this may get them fired). The surest way to prevent this from happening is to follow the crowd.

As long as people have different opinions, i.e. no one group of traders dominates, the market is in a state of disorder. Participants' actions tend to counteract each other and the market is stable. When any one group dominates order is created in the market. Many traders agree and take the same action. Their actions reinforce each other and in the case of a dominance of optimistic (or pessimistic) noise traders, exaggerate market movements away from the fundamental value. It is the actions of fundamental traders, who then act on the mispricing, that drives the prices back toward fundamental value. These models thus explain intermittent waves of optimism and pessimism. The data generated appear to fit the stylized facts.

Caveat

Dynamical systems models are analytically intractable. We need to be happy with either grossly oversimplified models or else only approximate or simulated results. Even the more complicated models are a drastic oversimplification of reality. They may provide a useful explanatory tool, but applying them in a useful way, may still be a way off. Although I have heard of trading being done with chaos theory models, I do not know what form they take. There is certainly a lot interesting research that can still be done.

One important point that must be made is that these models do not (and cannot) prove that the efficient markets hypothesis (EMH) is incorrect. In fact, none of the stylized facts I mentioned contradict the EMH (they do however contradict the far stronger notion that markets follow a random walk). Human behaviour, at least, is partly observable (maybe even quantifiable) whereas the supposed news process driving fundamental prices is far more ethereal. If the source of market turmoil is primarily from trader behaviour, then we may hope to curtail it by appropriate policies and education. However, very little can be done if it follows from fundamental processes.

Disclaimer

I do not fully understand the models I have written about myself. I do not (yet) have the necessary mathematical knowledge. If you want to know more please see the essay I wrote which gives a more in depth discussion and references.

References

Please see my essay on this topic.

2012/01/22

Imaginary Alpha

Alpha is what hedge funds sell. It is the skill of the investment manager(s), allowing them to earn a higher return than justified merely by the amount of risk they take. In practice this means earning more than a simple index fund. For this excess return, hedge funds charge higher fees. Presumably this is justified. In an efficient market alpha would be zero – there would be no way to earn (on average) higher returns than the market as a whole. No one (except economists and some MBA students) believes markets are efficient anymore. However, since 1998, hedge fund clients (in the US) have earned on average only half the rate of return on treasuries.

Self-selection bias

Indices of hedge fund performance suffer from a crucial flaw which make them (in my opinion) all but useless. Reporting to the indices is voluntary. And as such only hedge funds that perform well will start to report. Those that perform badly will stop reporting. The indices thus overstate hedge fund returns.

It has been argued that this may well be offset by the fact that the top-performing hedge funds may also choose not to report. They may do so because they have already raised enough capital or because they no longer need the exposure.

It would, however, appear that the latter effect is far smaller than the former, making any studies based on this data (which is most studies up to this point) suspect.

Damnation

A recent study by Aiken, Clifford and Ellis indicates that hedge fund alpha may well be much lower than previously thought. They find that, in fact, most of the alpha of hedge funds is explained by their decision to report (or not) in the commercial indices. In order to get past the self—selection problem they use the figures of funds of funds registered with the Securities and Exchange Commission. These funds invest in other hedge funds, whose returns can thus be scrutinised.

Funds that stop reporting afterward have dramatically lower returns than those that continue. The delisted funds continue to operate for some time and contribute zero alpha. This would still mean a positive alpha for hedge funds overall, but smaller than given by only examining the reporting funds.

Why not invest only in funds that do report returns? The hedge fund sector is illiquid – it takes time to get your money out. There is also a lag in the reporting of returns. An investor cannot be sure that a hedge will report its most recent returns.

Another problem (not tackled by the paper) is that some funds may perform well when they are small, which allows them to attract more money. This performance may or may not be simply due to luck. However, when (not if) the fund performs badly, its cash losses may well exceed all previous gains, simply because it now has more money. Investors, on average, lose out.

The above can be applied to the industry as a whole. When it was small, it was making high returns, and attracted capital from various sources. However, the losses in 2008, may have wiped out all cumulative gains in the industry going back ten years.

Caveats

The Aiken, Clifford and Ellis paper does suffer from flaws and these should be considered when evaluating the results. For instance, the period studied is from 2004 to 2009. It may be that a longer time period (or a future time period) gives different results. There is at least one study that finds no evidence of a selection bias due to the fact that funds that perform well may choose to stop reporting after having raised sufficient capital. The Aiken, Clifford and Ellis study itself has a selection bias, in that it only examines hedge funds that are invested in by funds of funds reporting to the SEC. The authors do, however, perform various tests which suggest that this results in no systematic errors. The statistical methods used are based on normal theory and as returns patently do not follow normal distributions, results should be treated with some scepticism. However, this latter point applies to most financial papers.

The dilemma

Hedge fund managers earn very large fees. They have done so, despite that their clients have walked away with meagre returns. This raises the question of whether the alpha displayed by some managers is anything more than mere luck. People have trouble believing in luck. They attribute high returns to skill. This is good for hedge fund managers, but it may be very bad for investors.

Some references
  • Aiken, A. L., Clifford, C. P., & Ellis, J. (2010). Out of the dark: Hedge fund reporting biases and commercial databases. Finance.
  • The Economist. (2012a). Hedge fund returns: More damning data. The Economist. Retrieved January 21, 2012, from http://www.economist.com/blogs/buttonwood/2012/01/hedge-fund-returns?fsrc=scn/fb/wl/bl/moredamningdata
  • The Economist. (2012b). Rich managers, poor clients. The Economist. Retrieved January 21, 2012, from http://www.economist.com/node/21542452
  • Wikipedia. (2012). Alpha (investment). Wikipedia. Retrieved January 21, 2012, from http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Alpha_(investment)